Hide table of contents

Lafiya Nigeria commissioned Rethink Priorities to conduct a detailed cost-effectiveness analysis of its intervention. It trains women health workers to provide family planning counseling and distribute an injectable contraceptive called Sayana Press in remote parts of rural northern Nigeria. The researchers also conducted uncertainty analysis of their findings using Monte Carlo simulations.

Summary and Key Takeaways

  • We model the near-term cost-effectiveness (2024-2025) of Lafiya Nigeria’s (n.d.) intervention, in which they upskill trained female health workers to provide family planning counseling and distribute injectable contraceptives (Sayana Press, or DMPA-SC) to women in remote parts of rural northern Nigeria.
  • We estimate that the cost-effectiveness of the intervention is $19 per unintended pregnancy averted at the beginning of 2024, falling to $7 per unintended pregnancy by the end of 2025 when approximately calibrating the model to the current and planned rate of intervention scaling.
    • We provide additional cost-effectiveness estimates, including cost per DALY averted (maternal, child, total), death averted (maternal, child, total), couple-year protection, additional contraceptive user, unsafe abortion averted, and $1 increase in women’s income, which can be found here.
    • Our crude estimate of the effect of the intervention on women’s income suggests that increasing the income of women serviced by Lafiya Nigeria by $1 cost $1.20 at the beginning of 2024, and will decline to $0.20 by the end of 2025. Reproducing GiveWell’s approach to understanding these benefits in terms of multiples of cash transfers, we find that the intervention’s impact on income increases from approximately 11x cash transfers at the beginning of 2024, increasing to 53x cash transfers by the end of 2025.
  • We conduct uncertainty analysis using a Monte Carlo simulation to gain insight into the effect of uncertainties from 15 inputs/factors on our cost-effectiveness estimates (Figure 1).
    • Looking at the effect of uncertainty on cost per unintended pregnancy averted, in Q1 2024 the 90% highest density interval (HDI) falls in the range of $17-$20 per unintended pregnancy averted (mean cost-effectiveness is ~$18). This uncertainty narrows over time, with a 90% HDI between $3.50 and $4.30 in Q4 2025 (mean cost-effectiveness is ~$4).
    • Uncertainties affect our cost-effectiveness estimation for other modeled outcomes similarly, except for the intervention’s impacts on income in multiples of cash where significant uncertainty in this estimate results in quite wide HDIs, getting wider over time with mean cost-effectiveness estimates growing from 10.8x (90% HDI 4.7x, 17.5x) in Q1 2024 to 49.9x (90% HDI 22.2x, 81.8x) in Q4 2025.
    • Overall, our uncertainty analysis did not show significant variation in estimates and therefore increases our confidence in the findings of the model.

Figure 1: Uncertainty analysis summary statistics for multiple outcomes. Points represent the mean of the Monte Carlo simulation (as do numbers on the outside of the ring), with error bars representing the 90% HDI. Numbers on the inside of the ring represent the year and quarter for each estimate.

Acknowledgments

Rethink Priorities’ Greer Gosnell and Jamie Elsey wrote this report under the supervision of Tom Hird. Rethink Priorities is a research and implementation group that identifies pressing opportunities to make the world better. We act upon these opportunities by developing and implementing strategies, projects, and solutions to key issues. We do this work in close partnership with foundations and impact-focused nonprofits. We thank Lafiya Nigeria for commissioning and funding this research report. The views expressed here are not necessarily endorsed by Lafiya Nigeria. We are grateful for the invaluable input of our interviewees, and for the support and data that Klau Chmielowska and Céline Kamsteeg of Lafiya Nigeria provided throughout the project.

We invite you to explore more RP research via our database and stay updated on new work by subscribing to our newsletter.
 

Read the report on Rethink Priorities' website

 

Download the report as a PDF
Comments15


Sorted by Click to highlight new comments since:

Thank you for your hard work on this report, Rethink Priorities team! I would be happy to be a point of contact if anyone has any questions regarding Lafiya's model or internal inputs used for the analysis.

$1 increase in women’s income

What kind of income is this? Monthly, yearly, lifetime?

Thanks for sharing. Do you think children born from unwanted pregnancies have positive lives? If so, would the family planning intervention still be beneficial accounting for the welfare loss of the children who would have been born from the prevented unwanted pregnancies? This seems like a crucial consideration.

I remember the Collins’ being emphatically pro abortion and contraception to increase the cultural prestige and frequency of having children - so the poster couple of population=good seems to think contraception and abortion access does not reduce the population, all things considered. I’m not sure if the lives of unwanted children are worth starting, but I should flag that I’m generally pessimistic about which lives are worth starting.

Edit: I’m not familiar with the culture of Nigeria. My intuitions about this developed in a western context and maybe there are relevant differences in Nigeria.

Thanks for the comment. Joey Savoie, the director of strategy of Charity Entrepreneurship, which incubated Lafiya Nigeria, said:

I am far less convinced that life saving interventions are net population creating than I am that family planning decreases it.

It looks like life saving interventions decrease fertility, but still increase population. So the above suggests family planning interventions do decrease population.

The section “How Many People Have Positive Wellbeing?” of Chapter 9 of What We Owe the Future mentions a few data points about neutral life satisfaction:

The relative nature of the scale means that it is difficult to interpret where the neutral point should be, and unfortunately, there have been only two small studies directly addressing this question. Respondents from Ghana and Kenya put the neutral point at 0.6, while one British study places it between 1 and 2.

I think Nigeria is more like Ghana and Kenya than the United Kingdom, so people in Nigeria may put the neutral point at around 0.6. From the 2024 World Happiness Report, Nigeria had a mean life satisfaction from 2021 to 2023 of 4.88, which is significantly higher than 0.6. I assume unwanted pregnancies will be more frequent in families with life satisfaction below the mean, but 4.88 is 8.13 times (= 4.88/0.6) as large as 0.6, so I expect a random child that would have been born from a prevented unwanted pregnancy to have a positive life.

My low confidence best guess is that Lafiya Nigeria decreases human welfare after accounting for the effect above. Difference assumptions may lead to different conclusions, but I believe one should at least discuss the potential loss of welfare of the children whose lives are prevented.

I would be curious to know your thoughts, @Klau Chmielowska. Thanks anyway for your hardwork.

How about modeling the flow through effects on animal welfare? This may negate any decrease in human welfare, but I haven't seen a BOTEC of this that models the income increase on the meat eating problem. I suspect it would likely still be very positive for animal welfare.

Thanks for the comment, Nithin. 

This may negate any decrease in human welfare, but I haven't seen a BOTEC of this that models the income increase on the meat eating problem.

As suggested by the graph below, the increased income of the helped families will tend to increase their consumption of animals, which is harmful if animals have negative lives.

However, since I think family planning interventions decrease human population, I believe they decrease the consumption of animals. Yet, I am not sure this is good because farmed animals' lives may become net positive in the next few decades, and the children who would be born from unwanted pregancies would live longer than that.

In any case, I worry the meat-eater problem is mostly a distraction. If one values 1 unit of welfare in animals as much as 1 unit of welfare in humans, and does not think Rethink Priorities' welfare ranges are wildly off, the best animal welfare interventions will be much more cost-effective than the best global health and development interventions. I estimate the cost-effectiveness of Shrimp Welfare Project’s (SWP’s) Humane Slaughter Initiative (HSI) is 64.3 k times that of GiveWell's top charities.

Hmm, I hadn't considered farmed animals lives becoming net positive as a case against the meat eating problem! Thanks for pointing that out.

> the best animal welfare interventions will be much more cost-effective than the best global > health and development interventions.

I'm a bit confused by this point. It still seems like if we value this framework, we should still be considering flow-through effects in questions of cause prioritization and which GHD interventions to support. I think there are also reasonable edge cases where we may be able to influence GHD interventions to have better positive flow-through effects, if the donor is not onboard with AW.

You are welcome!

we should still be considering flow-through effects in questions of cause prioritization and which GHD interventions to support. I think there are also reasonable edge cases where we may be able to influence GHD interventions to have better positive flow-through effects, if the donor is not onboard with AW.

Agreed. By "I worry the meat-eater problem is mostly a distraction", I meant a distraction for cause prioritisation. My sense is that people (like me) who consider the meat-eater problem to be a relevant consideration for prioritising within global health and development value 1 unit welfare in humans sufficiently similarly to 1 unit of welfare in animals to conclude that the best animal welfare interventions are much more cost-effective than the best human welfare interventions.

Vasco, where do you stand on the worry that farmed animal welfare interventions might be bad because less farmed animals=more wild animals, and wild animals have net negative lives. (I'm thinking any interventions that raise costs for farms might reduce meat consumption, and therefore number of farmed animals, at least a bit.) 

Interesting question, David!

I think it is very unclear whether wild animals have positive/negative lives, so I guess it is fine to neglect the effects on wild animals of interventions aiming to improve the welfare of farmed animals or humans. I have posted about these effects, and I believe their discussion can still be useful as a way of raising awareness for wild animal welfare.

In addition, as with the meat-eater problem, I suspect the effects on wild animals are mostly a distraction for cause prioritisation. If one is confident the effects on wild animals are positive/negative, and that their magnitude is significant, then I would expect interventions explicitly aiming to improve the welfare of wild animals to be more cost-effective than those targetting farmed animals or humans.

Wow, thank you for this. You're far more across this topic than I am, haha. 

As for the effects of family planning on population levels, it's interesting that there's such wide disagreement, although maybe it's just that the Collins' are mistaken (wouldn't shock me). I'd have to dig into the underlying research. 

I distrust self-reports as a reliable guide in this case due to various biases (discussed by Kahneman), and my thoughts on that have been much better expressed in chapter 4 of the human predicament. I'll need to revisit chapter 9 of WWOTF and see how their arguments and evidence compare. I would agree that an absence of positive lives (wherever the right line is) is somewhat bad, and should be a factor in decision making, although I am not a totalist or even a consequentialist (for example, I think the threshold for a live worth starting is quite above a life worth continuing). I agree that for totalists, this issue matters a lot, and for anyone uncertain about population ethics, it matters somewhat. 

To clarify for certain readers, I think that the right of the woman to family planning comes first and shouldn't be restricted. I think that foregone positive lives only has implications for prioritising among our positive obligations, not negative rights or liberties. I'm sure you agree. 

To clarify for certain readers, I think that the right of the woman to family planning comes first and shouldn't be restricted. I think that foregone positive lives only has implications for prioritising among our positive obligations, not negative rights or liberties. I'm sure you agree.

My views are pretty close to Ariel Simnegar's.

[comment deleted]2
0
0
Curated and popular this week
 ·  · 20m read
 · 
Advanced AI could unlock an era of enlightened and competent government action. But without smart, active investment, we’ll squander that opportunity and barrel blindly into danger. Executive summary See also a summary on Twitter / X. The US federal government is falling behind the private sector on AI adoption. As AI improves, a growing gap would leave the government unable to effectively respond to AI-driven existential challenges and threaten the legitimacy of its democratic institutions. A dual imperative → Government adoption of AI can’t wait. Making steady progress is critical to: * Boost the government’s capacity to effectively respond to AI-driven existential challenges * Help democratic oversight keep up with the technological power of other groups * Defuse the risk of rushed AI adoption in a crisis → But hasty AI adoption could backfire. Without care, integration of AI could: * Be exploited, subverting independent government action * Lead to unsafe deployment of AI systems * Accelerate arms races or compress safety research timelines Summary of the recommendations 1. Work with the US federal government to help it effectively adopt AI Simplistic “pro-security” or “pro-speed” attitudes miss the point. Both are important — and many interventions would help with both. We should: * Invest in win-win measures that both facilitate adoption and reduce the risks involved, e.g.: * Build technical expertise within government (invest in AI and technical talent, ensure NIST is well resourced) * Streamline procurement processes for AI products and related tech (like cloud services) * Modernize the government’s digital infrastructure and data management practices * Prioritize high-leverage interventions that have strong adoption-boosting benefits with minor security costs or vice versa, e.g.: * On the security side: investing in cyber security, pre-deployment testing of AI in high-stakes areas, and advancing research on mitigating the ris
 ·  · 15m read
 · 
In our recent strategy retreat, the GWWC Leadership Team recognised that by spreading our limited resources across too many projects, we are unable to deliver the level of excellence and impact that our mission demands. True to our value of being mission accountable, we've therefore made the difficult but necessary decision to discontinue a total of 10 initiatives. By focusing our energy on fewer, more strategically aligned initiatives, we think we’ll be more likely to ultimately achieve our Big Hairy Audacious Goal of 1 million pledgers donating $3B USD to high-impact charities annually. (See our 2025 strategy.) We’d like to be transparent about the choices we made, both to hold ourselves accountable and so other organisations can take the gaps we leave into account when planning their work. As such, this post aims to: * Inform the broader EA community about changes to projects & highlight opportunities to carry these projects forward * Provide timelines for project transitions * Explain our rationale for discontinuing certain initiatives What’s changing  We've identified 10 initiatives[1] to wind down or transition. These are: * GWWC Canada * Effective Altruism Australia funding partnership * GWWC Groups * Giving Games * Charity Elections * Effective Giving Meta evaluation and grantmaking * The Donor Lottery * Translations * Hosted Funds * New licensing of the GWWC brand  Each of these is detailed in the sections below, with timelines and transition plans where applicable. How this is relevant to you  We still believe in the impact potential of many of these projects. Our decision doesn’t necessarily reflect their lack of value, but rather our need to focus at this juncture of GWWC's development.  Thus, we are actively looking for organisations and individuals interested in taking on some of these projects. If that’s you, please do reach out: see each project's section for specific contact details. Thank you for your continued support as we
 ·  · 3m read
 · 
We are excited to share a summary of our 2025 strategy, which builds on our work in 2024 and provides a vision through 2027 and beyond! Background Giving What We Can (GWWC) is working towards a world without preventable suffering or existential risk, where everyone is able to flourish. We do this by making giving effectively and significantly a cultural norm. Focus on pledges Based on our last impact evaluation[1], we have made our pledges –  and in particular the 🔸10% Pledge – the core focus of GWWC’s work.[2] We know the 🔸10% Pledge is a powerful institution, as we’ve seen almost 10,000 people take it and give nearly $50M USD to high-impact charities annually. We believe it could become a norm among at least the richest 1% — and likely a much wider segment of the population — which would cumulatively direct an enormous quantity of financial resources towards tackling the world’s most pressing problems.  We initiated this focus on pledges in early 2024, and are doubling down on it in 2025. In line with this, we are retiring various other initiatives we were previously running and which are not consistent with our new strategy. Introducing our BHAG We are setting ourselves a long-term Big Hairy Audacious Goal (BHAG) of 1 million pledgers donating $3B USD to high-impact charities annually, which we will start working towards in 2025. 1 million pledgers donating $3B USD to high-impact charities annually would be roughly equivalent to ~100x GWWC’s current scale, and could be achieved by 1% of the world’s richest 1% pledging and giving effectively. Achieving this would imply the equivalent of nearly 1 million lives being saved[3] every year. See the BHAG FAQ for more info. Working towards our BHAG Over the coming years, we expect to test various growth pathways and interventions that could get us to our BHAG, including digital marketing, partnerships with aligned organisations, community advocacy, media/PR, and direct outreach to potential pledgers. We thin