This is a special post for quick takes by D0TheMath. Only they can create top-level comments. Comments here also appear on the Quick Takes page and All Posts page.
Sorted by Click to highlight new quick takes since:

I saw this comment on LessWrong

This seems noncrazy on reflection.

10 million dollars will probably have very small impact on Terry Tao's decision to work on the problem. 

OTOH, setting up an open invitation for all world-class mathematicians/physicists/theoretical computer science to work on AGI safety through some sort of sabbatical system may be very impactful.

Many academics, especially in theoretical areas where funding for even the very best can be scarce, would jump at the opportunity of a no-strings-attached sabbatical. The no-strings-attached is crucial to my mind. Despite LW/Rationalist dogma equating IQ with weirdo-points, the vast majority of brilliant (mathematical) minds are fairly conventional - see Tao, Euler, Gauss. 

EA cause area?

Thoughts? 

I don't know what the standard approach would be. I haven't read any books on evolutionary biology. I did listen to a bit of this online lecture series: https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=NNnIGh9g6fA&list=PL848F2368C90DDC3D and it seems fun & informative.

I’ve been using the models I’ve been learning to understand the problems associated with inner alignment to model evolution during this discussion, as it is a stochastic gradient descent process, so many of the arguments for properties that trained models should have can be applied to evolutionary processes.

So I guess you can start with Hubinger et al’s Risks from Learned Optimization? But this seems a nonstandard approach to trying to learn evolutionary biology.

Do you feel it is possible for evolution to select for beings who care about their copies in Everett branches, over beings that don't? For the purposes of this question let's say we ignore the "simplicity" complication of the previous point, and assume both species have been created, if that is possible.

It likely depends on what it means for evolution to select for something, and for a species to care about it's copies in other Everett branches. It's plausible to imagine a very low-amplitude Everett branch which has a species that uses quantum mechanical bits to make many of it's decisions, which decreases its chances of reproducing in most Everett branches, but increases it's chances of reproducing in very very few.

But in order for something to care about it's copies in other Everett branches, the species would need to be able to model how quantum mechanics works, as well as how acausal trade works if you want it to be able to be selected for caring how it's decision making process will affect non-causally-reachable Everett branches. I can't think of any pathways for how a species could increase it's inclusive genetic fitness by making acausal trades with it's counterparts in non-causally-reachable Everett branches, but I also can't think of any proof for why it's impossible. Thus, I only think it's unlikely.

For the case where we only care about selecting for caring about future Everett branches, note that if we find ourselves in the situation I described in the original post, and the proposal succeeds, then evolution has just made a minor update towards species which care about their future Everett selves.

Evolution doesn't select for that, but it's also important to note that such tendencies are not disselected for, and the value "care about yourself, and others" is simpler than the value "care about yourself, and others except those in other Everett branches", so we should expect people to generalize "others" as including those in Everett branches, in the same way that they generalize "others" as including those in the far future.

Also, while you cannot meaningfully influence Everett branches which have split off in the past, you can influence Everett branches that will split off some time in the future.

I’m not certain. I’m tempted to say I care about them in proportion to their “probabilities” of occurring, but if I knew I was on a very low-“probability” branch & there was a way to influence a higher “probability” branch at some cost to this branch, then I’m pretty sure I’d weight the two equally.

Are there any obvious reasons why this line of argument is wrong:

Suppose Everett interpretation of qm is true, and an x-risk curtailing humanity's future is >99% certain, with no leads on the solution to it. Then, given a qm bit generator, which generates some high number of bits, for any particular combination of bits, there exists a universe in which that combination was generated. In particular, the combination of bits encoding actions one can take to solve the x-risk are generated in some world. Thus, one should use such a qm bit generator to generate a plan to stop the x-risk. Even though you will likely see a bunch of random letters, there will exist a version of you with a good plan, and the world will not end.

One may argue the chances of finding a plan which produces an s-risk is just as high as one curtailing the x-risk. This only seems plausible to me if the solution produced is some optimization process, or induces some optimization process. These scenarios should not be discounted.

Curated and popular this week
 ·  · 4m read
 · 
Forethought[1] is a new AI macrostrategy research group cofounded by Max Dalton, Will MacAskill, Tom Davidson, and Amrit Sidhu-Brar. We are trying to figure out how to navigate the (potentially rapid) transition to a world with superintelligent AI systems. We aim to tackle the most important questions we can find, unrestricted by the current Overton window. More details on our website. Why we exist We think that AGI might come soon (say, modal timelines to mostly-automated AI R&D in the next 2-8 years), and might significantly accelerate technological progress, leading to many different challenges. We don’t yet have a good understanding of what this change might look like or how to navigate it. Society is not prepared. Moreover, we want the world to not just avoid catastrophe: we want to reach a really great future. We think about what this might be like (incorporating moral uncertainty), and what we can do, now, to build towards a good future. Like all projects, this started out with a plethora of Google docs. We ran a series of seminars to explore the ideas further, and that cascaded into an organization. This area of work feels to us like the early days of EA: we’re exploring unusual, neglected ideas, and finding research progress surprisingly tractable. And while we start out with (literally) galaxy-brained schemes, they often ground out into fairly specific and concrete ideas about what should happen next. Of course, we’re bringing principles like scope sensitivity, impartiality, etc to our thinking, and we think that these issues urgently need more morally dedicated and thoughtful people working on them. Research Research agendas We are currently pursuing the following perspectives: * Preparing for the intelligence explosion: If AI drives explosive growth there will be an enormous number of challenges we have to face. In addition to misalignment risk and biorisk, this potentially includes: how to govern the development of new weapons of mass destr
jackva
 ·  · 3m read
 · 
 [Edits on March 10th for clarity, two sub-sections added] Watching what is happening in the world -- with lots of renegotiation of institutional norms within Western democracies and a parallel fracturing of the post-WW2 institutional order -- I do think we, as a community, should more seriously question our priors on the relative value of surgical/targeted and broad system-level interventions. Speaking somewhat roughly, with EA as a movement coming of age in an era where democratic institutions and the rule-based international order were not fundamentally questioned, it seems easy to underestimate how much the world is currently changing and how much riskier a world of stronger institutional and democratic backsliding and weakened international norms might be. Of course, working on these issues might be intractable and possibly there's nothing highly effective for EAs to do on the margin given much attention to these issues from society at large. So, I am not here to confidently state we should be working on these issues more. But I do think in a situation of more downside risk with regards to broad system-level changes and significantly more fluidity, it seems at least worth rigorously asking whether we should shift more attention to work that is less surgical (working on specific risks) and more systemic (working on institutional quality, indirect risk factors, etc.). While there have been many posts along those lines over the past months and there are of course some EA organizations working on these issues, it stil appears like a niche focus in the community and none of the major EA and EA-adjacent orgs (including the one I work for, though I am writing this in a personal capacity) seem to have taken it up as a serious focus and I worry it might be due to baked-in assumptions about the relative value of such work that are outdated in a time where the importance of systemic work has changed in the face of greater threat and fluidity. When the world seems to
Sam Anschell
 ·  · 6m read
 · 
*Disclaimer* I am writing this post in a personal capacity; the opinions I express are my own and do not represent my employer. I think that more people and orgs (especially nonprofits) should consider negotiating the cost of sizable expenses. In my experience, there is usually nothing to lose by respectfully asking to pay less, and doing so can sometimes save thousands or tens of thousands of dollars per hour. This is because negotiating doesn’t take very much time[1], savings can persist across multiple years, and counterparties can be surprisingly generous with discounts. Here are a few examples of expenses that may be negotiable: For organizations * Software or news subscriptions * Of 35 corporate software and news providers I’ve negotiated with, 30 have been willing to provide discounts. These discounts range from 10% to 80%, with an average of around 40%. * Leases * A friend was able to negotiate a 22% reduction in the price per square foot on a corporate lease and secured a couple months of free rent. This led to >$480,000 in savings for their nonprofit. Other negotiable parameters include: * Square footage counted towards rent costs * Lease length * A tenant improvement allowance * Certain physical goods (e.g., smart TVs) * Buying in bulk can be a great lever for negotiating smaller items like covid tests, and can reduce costs by 50% or more. * Event/retreat venues (both venue price and smaller items like food and AV) * Hotel blocks * A quick email with the rates of comparable but more affordable hotel blocks can often save ~10%. * Professional service contracts with large for-profit firms (e.g., IT contracts, office internet coverage) * Insurance premiums (though I am less confident that this is negotiable) For many products and services, a nonprofit can qualify for a discount simply by providing their IRS determination letter or getting verified on platforms like TechSoup. In my experience, most vendors and companies